Hierarchical Efficiency in Banking: Decentralized Bi-Level Programming with Stackelberg Dynamics
Abstract:
The inherent hierarchical and decentralized nature of decision-making within banking systems presents significant challenges in evaluating operational efficiency. This study introduces a novel bi-level programming (BLP) framework, incorporating Stackelberg equilibrium dynamics, to assess the performance of bank branches. By combining with data envelopment analysis (DEA), the proposed BLP-DEA model captures the leader-follower relationship that characterizes banking operations, wherein the leader focuses on marketability and the follower prioritizes profitability. A case study involving 15 Iranian bank branches was employed to demonstrate the model’s capacity to evaluate performance comprehensively at both decision-making levels. The results underscore the model's effectiveness in identifying inefficiencies, analyzing cost structures, and providing actionable insights for performance optimization. This approach offers a robust tool for addressing the complexities associated with decentralized decision-making in hierarchical organizations. The findings have significant implications for both theoretical development and practical application, especially in the context of improving the operational efficiency of banking institutions.
1. Introduction
In the swiftly evolving and technologically advanced realm of computers and telecommunications, where competition is fierce, banks, as one of the most intricate sectors globally, must possess the agility to respond promptly to changes. In a highly competitive landscape, ongoing enhancement is essential for any prosperous firm. Consequently, enhancing performance is universally acknowledged as crucial for achieving a competitive edge. The banking chain possesses a multifaceted and intricate structure due to its operation in a competitive business environment. The banking chain is pivotal in the economic cycle of each nation, and to achieve or keep a competitive advantage, performance evaluation has become a crucial responsibility for the management of every financial institution. Consequently, in evaluating bank branch performance, the primary emphasis of this study has grown increasingly complex due to variations in size, the provision of diverse services to distinct clientele, and a multi-faceted structure. Two methodologies were employed in this study to assess the operational effectiveness of bank branches: parametric and non-parametric. The disadvantage of parametric approaches lies in several intrinsic restrictions that render them inadequate for accurately representing the increasingly intricate nature of banking networks.
Regression analysis, a premier parametric methodology, serves as a method of central tendency and is exclusively applicable for modeling single input-multiple outputs or multiple inputs-single output systems. DEA, a non-parametric methodology, serves as a superior tool for efficiency analysis by establishing an efficient production frontier to evaluate the Decision-Making Units (DMUs) in relation to the optimal ones operating under identical conditions [1]. The capability to manage many inputs and outputs is a compelling advantage that distinguishes DEA from other analytical instruments. The standard DEA assesses the relative efficiency of DMUs considering numerous inputs and outputs without adequate details for managerial decision-making [2]. In practical situations, corporations (DMUs) consist of multiple divisions or levels, characterized by significant inter-level interactions that are interconnected and adhere to multi-tiered Stackelberg linkages. The intricate hierarchical framework of banking institutions presents obstacles for their managers. Managers face significant issues related to fluctuating costs and demand within multi-level Stackelberg relationships, necessitating the coordination of these interactions to deliver high-quality services to clients. Bank managers can enhance cost efficiency by sustaining or elevating service quality to establish a competitive edge.
The cost efficiency of banking chains assesses their capacity to generate current outputs at minimal costs, offering insights into the managerial oversight of overall operational expenses. The evaluation of banking branch performance inherently presents a hierarchical multi-level decision modeling challenge. In multi-level decentralized decision-making organizations, each level often governs its own set of decision variables, which frequently have conflicting objectives. Consequently, the assessment of banking chain performance is conducted from several perspectives. Performance assessment within this specific multi-tiered decentralized decision framework can be represented by a BLP-DEA methodology [3]. This methodology operates as a black box. It represents the internal framework and internal dynamics of a system with a hierarchical organization. BLP-DEA can offer useful insights and comprehensive information to managers when assessing the operation of a system characterized by Stackelberg-game dynamics [4]. This study aims to demonstrate a rarely employed non-parametric analytical method known as BLP-DEA, which tackles the issue of cost efficiency assessment within Stackelberg leader-follower dynamics in the banking sector [5], [6].
The subsequent sections of this study are structured as follows: Section 2 presents a review of the literature. Section 3 presents the concepts of BLP and DEA cost efficiency. Section 4 presents the BLP-DEA model introduced by Wu [4]. Section 5 illustrates the practical use of the BLP-DEA model through a case study involving an Iranian bank. Conclusions are delineated in Section 6.
2. Research Background
Compared to methods for evaluating organizational performance, DEA introduced by Charnes et al. [7] offers a superior approach for data organization and analysis, as it accommodates variations in efficiency over time and does not necessitate prior assumptions regarding the specification of the efficient frontier. Consequently, DEA serves as a superior method for performance evaluation inside the banking sector. In numerous practical situations, DMUs exhibit a two-stage network process [1], [8], [9]. Consequently, DEA has been expanded to assess the efficiency of two-step processes, wherein all outputs from the initial stage serve as intermediate measures, constituting the inputs for the subsequent stage. Wang [10] delineated a two-step process within the banking sector, wherein banks utilize inputs such as fixed assets, manpower, and information technology (IT) investments in the initial stage to create deposits. The banks utilize the deposits as an intermediary measure to produce loans and profits as outputs. Bhattacharya et al. [11] employed a two-stage DEA methodology to analyze the influence of liberalization on the efficiency of the Indian banking sector. A technical efficiency score was computed in the initial step.
Conversely, in the subsequent step, a stochastic frontier analysis was employed to ascribe variations in efficiency scores to the following sources: ownership, temporal, and noise components. Seiford and Zhu [12] analyzed the performance of the leading 55 US banks employing a two-stage DEA methodology. Findings revealed that larger banks demonstrate superior profitability, whereas smaller banks excel in marketability. Sexton and Lewis [13] presented a bifurcated methodology for assessing Major League Baseball performance. Kao and Hwang [14] proposed an alternative method in which the complete two-stage process can be expressed as the product of the efficiencies of the two subprocesses.
Consequently, the overall efficiency and the efficiency of each stage can be determined. Tone and Tsutsui [15] expanded the Slacks-Based Measure (SBM) model into a network architecture to address intermediate products formally. Avkiran [16], as the inaugural empirical investigation of Network Slacks-Based Measure (NSBM), utilized actual aggregate data from domestic commercial banks in the United Arab Emirates and employed the non-oriented NSBM to assess profit efficiency. Fukuyama and Weber [17] expanded the slacks-based inefficiency metric to assess a two-stage system with undesirable outputs at a Japanese bank. Paradi et al. [18] devised a two-stage DEA methodology for concurrently evaluating the performance of operational units. Li et al. [19] introduced a non-cooperative, centralized model to assess the efficiency of a two-stage process, aiming to deconstruct the overall efficiency of intricate network topologies.
Bi-level decision-making, or BLP techniques, initially described by Von Stackelberg et al. [20], have been primarily developed to address decentralized decision processes involving decision-makers inside a hierarchical organization. The individual responsible for decision-making in the upper echelon is referred to as the leader, whereas at the lower tier, the followers possess their own potentially conflicting aims. BLP has been utilized in numerous domains. Ryu et al. [21] introduced a BLP paradigm to address the competing interests of several constituents in supply chain planning issues. Sun et al. [22] introduced a BLP model to address the location problem, considering the interests of both customers and logistics planners. Sakawa et al. [23] addressed a transportation issue in a housing material manufacturing firm and obtained an acceptable resolution to the problem. Roghanian et al. [24] examined a probabilistic bi-level linear multi-objective programming issue and its application in comprehensive supply chain planning within enterprises. Arora and Gupta [25] introduced an interactive fuzzy goal programming methodology for BLP issues exhibiting dynamic programming traits. Lan et al. [26] developed two inventory control models for degrading items, utilizing time- and quantity-based integrated delivery strategies for suppliers within the Vendor-Managed Inventory (VMI) paradigm, grounded in BLP.
Wu [4] devised a novel quantitative methodology to assess the efficacy of multi-level decision network structures by incorporating cost DEA into a BLP framework and formulating a BLP-DEA model. To illustrate the model's applicability, Wu [4] presented its use in two real cases: a banking chain and a manufacturing supply chain.
3. Fundamentals of BLP and DEA Cost Efficiency
Diverse DEA models with varying objectives have been established [27]. The primary objective of most DEA models is to analyze the technical and physical dimensions of production in contexts where unit pricing and unit cost data are either unknown or constrained due to fluctuations in the relevant prices and costs. The cost efficiency model demonstrates the capacity of DMUs to generate current outputs at minimal costs and illustrates how DEA can detect potential inefficiencies when precise cost information is available [28], [29].
Let there be $n$ DMUs under assessment, denoted as $j=1, \ldots, n$; the input vector is denoted as $X=$ $\left(x_1, \ldots, x_m\right)^T$ which generates the output vector $Y=\left(y_1, \ldots, y_s\right)^T$ within the production possibility set. Accordingly, the cost efficiency model for the $0^{\text {th }}$ DMU $(0 \in\{1, \ldots, n\})$ can be articulated as follows:
where, $x_i$ and $\lambda_j$ represent decision variables; and $c_i$ is the unit cost of input $i$, which may differ among several DMUs. This model permits substitutions in inputs. The model's goal function is to reduce the total cost of the $0^{\text {th }} \mathrm{DMU}$.
Based on an optimal solution $\left(x^*, \lambda^*\right)$ of the above linear programming, the cost efficiency of DMU$_0$ is defined as:
where, $X_0$ is the input vector of DMU$_0$.
BLP, inspired by Stackelberg's game theory [20], pertains to scenarios involving two decision-makers inside an organization who are linked in a hierarchical framework [30]. In these circumstances, the individual who initially renders a decision is referred to as the leader, while the one who, aware of the opponent's decision, then makes a decision is designated as the follower. These two decision-makers possess independent, potentially conflicting, objectives. Within the framework of BLP, the leader initially delineates a decision. The follower, fully aware of the leader's decision, chooses to optimize their objective function.
Consequently, the leader also makes decisions to optimize their objective function. The solution derived from the approach mentioned above is a Stackelberg equilibrium solution [31]. A bi-level linear programming (BLLP) problem is formulated to derive the Stackelberg solution as follows:
where, $c_i(i=1,2)$ denote the $n_1$-dimensional row coefficient vector, while $d_i(i=1,2)$ represent the $n_2$-dimensional vector. Furthermore, coefficient matrices $A$ and $B$ are $m \times n_1$ and $m \times n_2$, and $b$ is an $m$-dimensional column constant vector. In addition, $z_1(x, y)$ and $z_2(x, y)$ represent the leader's and follower's objective functions, respectively; $x$ and $y$ represent a collection of decision variables governed by the leader and the follower [31].
Definition 1. $S$ represents the BLLP problem's feasible region [31]:
\[S=\{(x, y) \mid A x+B y \leq b, x \geq 0, y \geq 0\}\]
Definition 2. $S(x)$ is the follower decision space after $x$ is specified by the leader [31]:
\[S(x)=\{y \geq 0 \mid B y \leq b-A x, x \geq 0\}\]
Definition 3. $S_X$ is the leader decision space [31]:
\[S_X=\{x \geq 0 \mid \text { there is a } y \text { such that } A x+B y \leq b, y \geq 0\}\]
Definition 4. $R(x)$ denotes the set of follower rational responses for $x$ designated by the leader [31]:
\[R(x)=\left\{y \geq 0 \mid y \in \arg \min _{y \in S(x)} z_2(x, y)\right\}\]
Definition 5. Inducible region [31]:
\[I R=\{(x, y) \mid(x, y) \in S, y \in R(x)\}\]
Definition 6. Stackelberg solution [31]:
\[\left\{(x, y) \mid(x, y) \in \arg \min _{(x, y) \in I R} z_1(x, y)\right\}\]
In BLP, the follower optimization issue is regarded as a constraint within a bi-level optimization framework. By employing the Kuhn-Tucker methodology, a prevalent technique for addressing BLP, the follower's problem can be substituted with the Kuhn-Tucker conditions pertinent to the follower's issue. The leader's issue with limitations related to the optimality criteria of the follower's problem is subsequently resolved [31]. Utilizing Kuhn-Tucker conditions, the BLLP problem (3) can be reformulated as an equivalent single-level nonlinear programming (SLNLP) problem:
where, $u$ denotes an $m$-dimensional row vector, and $v$ represents an $n_2$-dimensional row vector. In addition, $u$ and $v$ stand for the dual variables related to constraints $A x+B y \leq b$ and $y \geq 0$.
By employing zero-one vectors $w_1=\left(w_{11}, \ldots, w_{1 m}\right)$ and $w_2=\left(w_{21}, \ldots, w_{2 n_2}\right)$, the NLP model can be converted into a linear mixed zero-one programming issue, which may be addressed using a zero-one mixed integer solution:
where, $e$ represents an $m$-dimensional vector of ones, and $M$ denotes a large positive constant. For more information, please refer to the study by Nishizaki and Sakawa [31].
4. The Proposed BLP-DEA Model
The evaluation of banking branch performance presents inherent challenges in two-level hierarchical decision modeling. In the banking hierarchy, the primary level gathers funds from consumers as deposits, while the secondary level utilizes these deposits to generate profit. The performance evaluation of banking branches can be treated as a leader-follower Stackelberg problem, as the money received at the first level influences the investment decisions at the second level [4]. Figure 1 illustrates the notional BLP-DEA model using shared resources.
Consider $n$ banking branches $(j=1, \ldots, n)$ comprising $L_1$ and $L_2$ levels, the $L_1-L_2$ chain was analyzed utilizing a BLP framework, with the initial level designated as the leader and the subsequent level as the follower. The performance evaluation issues of these two bank branch chains for a specific DMU$_0$ can be mathematically represented using the BLP-DEA model, which accounts for the hierarchical structure of the bank branches, incorporating the decision maker at each level who independently manages a set of decision variables, as follows:
where, $m_1$-dimensional $X^1$ denotes row vectors of the leader's shared input; $m_1$-dimensional $X^2$ denotes row vectors of the follower's shared input; $m_2$-dimensional $X^{D 1}$ represents the row vector of the leader's direct input; $m_3$-dimensional $X^{D 2}$ denotes the row vector of the follower's direct input; $m_4$-dimensional $Y^{I 1}$ represents a row vector, serving as the intermediate output to the leader and the intermediate input to the follower; $m_5$-dimensional $Y^1$ denotes the row vector of the leader's direct output; $m_6$-dimensional $Y^2$ stands for the row vector of the follower's direct output; $C^{1^T}, C^{2^T}, D^{1^T}$, and $D^{2^T}$ denote the input unit cost vectors associated with the shared input, the direct input to the leader, the direct input to the follower, and the intermediate input to the follower, respectively; and $\lambda$ and $\pi$ represent the nonnegative multiplier used to aggregate existing leader and follower activities [4].
The BLP-DEA model was converted into the mixed integer single-level linear programming DEA (SLLP-DEA) model as outlined below:
where, $U^1$ and $V^1$ denote the $m_1$-dimensional dual vectors corresponding to the follower's shared input constraints and variables; $U^2$ and $V^2$ represent the $m_3$-dimensional dual vectors concerning the follower's direct input constraints and variables; $U^3$ and $V^3$ denote the $m_4$-dimensional dual vectors corresponding to the follower's intermediate input constraints and variables; $U^4$ and $V^4$ represent the $n$-dimensional dual vectors; $U^5$ is an $m_1$-dimensional dual vector corresponding to the constrained resource constraint; $W_i^T(i=1, \ldots, 9)$ denotes the zero-one vectors; and $e$ and $M$ represent the vector of ones and the large positive constant.
By solving the BLP-DEA model, the optimal solutions of $\bar{X}^{1 *}, \bar{X}^{2 *}, \bar{X}^{D 1 *}, \bar{X}^{D 2 *}, \bar{Y}^{I 1 *}, \lambda_j{ }^*$, and $\pi_j{ }^*$ were obtained. Based on the optimal solutions, the cost efficiency of the leader of DMU$_0$ is defined as:
Furthermore, for DMU$_0$, the follower's cost efficiency is calculated as follows:
In addition, the total cost efficiency can be computed as follows:
5. Empirical Study
Banks can be regarded as organizations where two decision-makers within a hierarchical framework alternate in making decisions to enhance their performance. The proposed BLP-DEA model was employed to assess some Iranian banks' performance in 2011. Each branch consists of marketability and profitability, with marketability as the primary factor and profitability as the secondary factor. The marketability level reflects the branch's capacity to attract deposits from clients by utilizing bank resources for marketing purposes. The profitability level reflects the branch's capacity to generate profit by allocating deposit values to other operations. The performance evaluation index system for the bank branch is presented in Table 1.
Indicators | Name | Unit | Indicators | Name | Unit |
Leader | Follower | ||||
Shared input | Employees | Person | Shared input | Employees | Person |
Direct input | Fixed assets | 1,000,000,000 Riyal | Direct input | IT cost | 100,000,000 Riyal |
Space | m2 | ||||
Intermediate output | Deposit | 10,000,000,000 Riyal | Intermediate output | Deposit | 10,000,000,000 Riyal |
Output | Non-invest deposit | 100,000,000 Riyal | Output | Profit | 10,000,000,000 Riyal |
Input costs | Employees | 1,000,000 Riyal | Input cost | Employees | 1,000,000 Riyal |
Space | 1,000,000 Riyal |
Each branch's performance is represented by several variables: fixed assets $\left(X^{D 11}\right)$, space $\left(X^{D 12}\right)$, noninvest deposit $\left(Y^1\right)$ at the leader level, IT costs $\left(X^{D 2}\right)$ and profit $\left(Y^2\right)$ at the follower level. Deposit from leader to follower level $\left(Y^{I 1}\right)$ serves as an intermediate variable. Marketability $\left(X^1\right)$ and profitability $\left(X^2\right)$ are resource-shared variables. The data for these factors is shown in Table 2, presenting the costs associated with shared staff and space. Due to the fixed nature of assets, deposits, and IT expenses, these costs are assumed to be unit-based.
Utilizing the mixed integer SLLP-DEA model, cost efficiency scores of branches and followers and leaders were derived. Table 3 presents the cost efficiency scores and the reference units for both the leader and the follower.
Table 3 indicates that no banks are cost-efficient, as they do not operate effectively at both decision levels. The 10$^{\text {th }}$ and 11$^{\text {th }}$ banks exhibit cost efficiency at the leader tier, while the 1$^{\text {st }}$ and 3$^{\text {rd }}$ banks demonstrate cost efficiency at the follower tier. Due to the inefficiency of the other players in these banks, these banks are consistently classified as inefficient. Table 3 demonstrates that the 2$^{\text {nd }}$ bank exhibits greater efficiency than the 3$^{\text {rd }}$, 10$^{\text {th }}$, and 11$^{\text {th }}$ banks, which operate at a singular level of efficiency, highlighting the potential advantage of coordination among participants.
DMUs | Leader Employee | Fixed Asset | Space | Non-Invest Deposit | Deposit | Follower Employee | IT Cost | Profit | Employees Cost | Space Cost |
1 | 23 | 4.93 | 110 | 10.57 | 15.78 | 14 | 4.93 | 3.15 | 5.97 | 5.97 |
2 | 34 | 3.64 | 167.50 | 14.82 | 43.90 | 28 | 3.64 | 3.31 | 6.25 | 4.41 |
3 | 14 | 2.87 | 150 | 7.60 | 7.74 | 25 | 2.87 | 3.53 | 7.86 | 6.02 |
4 | 28 | 1.78 | 366.6 | 14.80 | 45.95 | 31 | 1.78 | 1.98 | 5.70 | 10.64 |
5 | 33 | 3.61 | 555 | 13.39 | 38.70 | 35 | 3.61 | 2.69 | 9.65 | 11.78 |
6 | 34 | 2.24 | 690 | 14.15 | 36.81 | 28 | 2.24 | 1.93 | 7.59 | 8.25 |
7 | 25 | 1.41 | 750.92 | 13.08 | 61.11 | 28 | 1.41 | 2.12 | 8.53 | 16.02 |
8 | 35 | 2.64 | 368.3 | 20.31 | 26.33 | 18 | 2.64 | 2.55 | 12.37 | 9.92 |
9 | 27 | 2.97 | 205 | 16.16 | 11.74 | 40 | 2.97 | 1.62 | 6.87 | 12.96 |
10 | 35 | 2.65 | 195 | 16.21 | 70.42 | 11 | 2.65 | 2.00 | 7.90 | 7.21 |
11 | 33 | 3.76 | 210 | 38.24 | 34.25 | 15 | 3.76 | 2.90 | 11.24 | 12.97 |
12 | 28 | 2.47 | 481 | 17.94 | 37.03 | 26 | 2.47 | 2.25 | 5.61 | 7.33 |
13 | 20 | 2.29 | 200 | 13.73 | 11.66 | 24 | 2.29 | 2.45 | 8.51 | 12.05 |
14 | 28 | 3.55 | 506 | 14.17 | 10.31 | 36 | 3.55 | 4.19 | 100.03 | 11.75 |
15 | 35 | 1.97 | 814 | 14.41 | 31.98 | 30 | 1.97 | 1.96 | 7.53 | 10.45 |
DMUs | Bank Cost Efficiency | Leader Cost Efficiency | Follower Cost Efficiency | Reference Set for the Leader | Reference Set for the Follower |
1 | 0.66 | 0.61 | 1.00 | 10, 11 | 1 |
2 | 0.50 | 0.90 | 0.70 | 10, 11 | 3 |
3 | 0.48 | 0.37 | 1.00 | 10, 11 | 3 |
4 | 0.14 | 0.41 | 0.28 | 10, 11 | 1 |
5 | 0.08 | 0.24 | 0.35 | 10, 11 | 1 |
6 | 0.10 | 0.20 | 0.31 | 10, 11 | 1 |
7 | 0.05 | 0.24 | 0.31 | 10 | 1 |
8 | 0.14 | 0.41 | 0.92 | 10, 11 | 3 |
9 | 0.19 | 0.54 | 0.29 | 11 | 3 |
10 | 0.32 | 1.00 | 0.52 | 10 | 1 |
11 | 0.18 | 1.00 | 0.79 | 11 | 1 |
12 | 0.15 | 0.33 | 0.52 | 10, 11 | 3 |
13 | 0.21 | 0.44 | 0.71 | 11 | 3 |
14 | 0.09 | 0.20 | 0.83 | 11 | 3 |
15 | 0.07 | 0.15 | 0.30 | 10, 11 | 1 |
6. Conclusions
In reality, banks operate with a decentralized framework where numerous decision-makers inside a hierarchical system make decisions sequentially or concurrently to optimize their goal function. In this swiftly evolving world, effective response to changes necessitates management's capacity to pinpoint inefficiencies. As a result, efficiency analysis can become a key tool for gaining a competitive edge. DEA is a superior method for assessing efficiency as it does not necessitate any preconceptions regarding the configuration of the efficient frontier. This study employs a BLP-DEA model, including two interconnected decision-makers inside a decentralized framework, to assess the performance of 15 Iranian bank branches, with one level representing a leader and the other a follower. The BLP-DEA model offers valuable insights and comprehensive information to bank management for assessing the efficiency of a bank inside Stackelberg-game dynamics. The outcomes derived from the BLP-DEA model exhibit significant discriminative capability by incorporating internal operations within the banking chain.
The data used to support the findings of this study are included within the article.
The authors declare that they have no conflicts of interest.